I recently read an article that mentioned how philosophy is intrinsically rooted in time:
“At the beginning of the nineteenth century Hegel wrote that every philosopher is a child of his time and none can jump over his own shadow: every philosophy, then, is “its time grasped in a concept.”… [Hegel] also holds that philosophy is essentially retrospective, a reflection of a historical moment or movement that when it finally takes philosophical form is essentially already over. This doctrine marks a distinction between what is “really” happening in the political, social and economic world and the subsequent reflection of this in philosophy (religion, art, law, etc.).”
-Raymond Guess, "The Idea of a Critical Theory"
This makes a lot of sense. By the time someone has been able to synthesize a full philosophy about a topic, it may have already past or become commonplace. An example I will use from a public policy standpoint is women’s right to vote. The suffrage movements began in the 1848, 72 years before women were given the right to vote in 1920. If you were just learning about this piece of law, you might not realize it had been an issue for 72 years, and by the time it was reflected in law had become quite well known/commonplace.
You can apply this reflection to almost any law—think about marijuana legalization, which is favored by a majority of Americans, but will have become a commonplace topic by the time it is approved on the federal level. The same goes for gay marriage, civil rights, abortion, and more. Any law is then essentially retrospective. Rarely are laws seen that aim to act for the future based off of no past—it just wouldn’t make sense!
So how does this relate to economics?
The same criticisms that can be applied to philosophy are relevant to economic models. The Lucas critique, made famous by Noble award-winner George Lucas, revolves around the idea that any economic policy based off of macroeconomic models and historical data will invalidate itself. When an economic policy is developed, macroeconomic models based on the current state and historic data are used to make policy predictions. Once the policy is implemented, however, the framework upon which the model is based is no longer relevant, as the current state has changed! This ultimately means that these models will be inaccurate and potentially not act as they were predicted to.
The Lucas critique is the precise reason that many economic policies struggle to have an effect. Unless a policy is modeled around individual behavior and preferences, then aggregated, we can’t predict what people will do. A model composed of the compiled preferences of millions of people (more microeconomic, think small) will inherently be more accurate than wild postulations about the economy without considering the people that make up that economy. As fun as it is to theorize about the implications of low interest rates¹, without including the people who will be affected by these rates in our model we could be totally wrong! Whether the topic is philosophy, economics, or politics, the most effective policies and beliefs will be shaped by considering individual actors rather than generalizing in the hope of achieving simplicity.
The Lucas critique duly traces back to the idea that philosophy and economics are very closely linked. Theories for both subjects are inherently rooted in their current time, and reflective of the past. Unfortunately, many people don’t seem to realize that while people like Adam Smith and Keynes were brilliant, their ideas are rooted in their own time! When you next hear a historic quote or philosophy, ask yourself how the climate of the era might have effected that belief.
Examining the context behind ideas is not only critical to understanding those vastly different from us in the present or past, but also to shaping the future. So next time you hear a past economic theory or old quote, try and think about how this idea might be relevant (or irrelevant) today. After all, we are all a “child of our time”.
¹It’s not that fun.
Popular mobile payments app Venmo enjoys the benefits of behavioral economics biases, causing users to feel less pain from spending money. Learn how it works, and how businesses can capture the "Venmo effect".
Deep-dive into the increasingly personal way we interact with brands, fueled by Snapchat and Instagram.
Some musings on the benefits of the changing cultural consumption landscape (including the shift to streaming of music and TV).
Females are prescribed psychiatric drugs at much higher rates than men. Females also tend to be more emotional (wide generalization). Processing emotions takes time, and time spent on emotional work is time NOT spent generating revenue. Ultimately, the trend of medicating female emotion (and emotion in general) is a money-driven one.
The Internet of Things (IoT) is the future of technology, but also represents some interesting economic phenomena not-so-frequently seen.
We all hate surge pricing, but it's a great way for Uber and its drivers to capture more value. What if GrubHub, Starbucks, etc. charged customers more during peak hours in order to pay service workers better? Could we ever break the cycle of reliance on cheap labor?
Price discrimination is a way that companies can make more money by understanding how much different consumers will pay for the same good. Here's how it works.
What's the economic explanation behind the rise of the term "basic"? Is this a new phenomenon, or merely a quality of human nature evident due to economic and technical changes?
Would you pay $35 for a Raspberry Pi? No, not the food, it's a miniature computer! This device can be revolutionary for the 75 million Americans without internet access.
Do you ever forget the difference between nominal and real? Do you wonder why financiers analyze Yellen's words like a text from a crush? If so, this is the article for you!
When fruit flies, it fails. Industrial agricultural practices have brought us berries in January, but at the cost of quality. Read about why harvesting heirloom varieties is important for taste, small farmers, and the environment.
It used to be that the strongest hunter had the most value in society. Today, the nerdy ideas man has the most worth. What happened?
Innovation is cyclical and inspired by other innovation. For example, this article was inspired by my purchase of innovative new ice cube trays. Read about how product variety is created, and how it can be a bad thing.
You may hear the terms horizontal and vertical integration tossed around in business (Businesspeople love fancy strategy terms). Learn how Standard Oil used integration to become a monopoly and how one might benefit from integration today.
Will a big engagement ring buy you happiness? What about donating blood? How do you properly motivate someone? If you are looking for a job, is city size a factor? Why are smartphones important for the poor to have? All this and more.
America is in trouble if the cost of Third World labor increases. As has been the tradition for all of human history, our economic success depends on the accessibility cheap and near-slave labor. How can we grow when this ends?
Some would claim that it is human nature to capitalize upon opportunities. Arbitrage was born of this human urge to take advantage of money-making opportunities.
Efficient appliances seem like a great way to reduce our energy use, right? Wrong - in the long run, they end up causing massive increases in energy use due to cost reductions.
"Run out of oil? Never!"
In all likelihood, this won't transpire, but if you aren't familiar with the idea of peak oil (or like to deny it), answer all your questions here.
Most people could tell you that oil and energy is critical to our economy and planet. In fact, energy is the foundation of all growth, but it isn't included in our economic models. Here's why the discipline of economics needs to be re-organized.
This edition of Deciphering Data brings you the answers to all these pressing questions and more:
- At what time of year do most break-ups happen?
- Why are tiger-moms a thing in the US and China?
- How do different people around the world think success happens?
The rise of American affluence gave us the luxury of choice and ability to be picky about what we like. Combined with newly formed marketing and advertising industries, consumer preferences developed that made perfect substitutes an economic unicorn. (If you don't know what a perfect substitute is, no worries, read on!)
Indifference curves are not graphs of who cares less, rather, they show different combinations of goods that can give a person a certain level of utility, or well-being.
Do middleman apps make our lives better? What about the lives of their employees? Do Uber-like services improve consumer welfare? How do recessions affect birth rates? Why does the US have relatively high infant mortality?
Find the answers to all these questions and more.
Does this man look like he is substituting or complementing these apples? Trick question: apples are inanimate, and can't be complimented.
The best data visualizations from around the web. Learn about online dating, music tastes, political preferences, violence, and earthquakes.
Did you know that higher gas prices might be better for us all? Industrialism is great, but creates negative externalities, such as pollution. Pigovian taxes reduce negative externalities and aim to also reduce distortionary taxes, like income tax. Win-win!
Don't be like this guy and let your money sit in the bank. Start investing with some simple tips!
Money represents a social agreement, which has implications for how we value wealthy people. Bitcoin replaces the need for this social agreement with technology, and in doing so challenges the values we ascribe to wealth.